Labels and Tags

Accountability (71) Adequate documentation (7) ADR in procurement (4) Allocation of risks (6) Best interest of government (11) Best practices (19) Best value (15) Bidder prejudice (11) Blanket purchase agreement (1) Bridge contract (2) Bundling (6) Cancellation and rejection (2) Centralized procurement structure (12) Changes during bid process (14) Clarifications vs Discussions (1) Competence (9) Competition vs Efficiency (29) Competitive position (3) Compliance (35) Conflict of interest (32) Contract administration (26) Contract disputes (4) Contract extension or modification (9) Contract formation (1) Contract interpretation (1) Contract terms (3) Contract types (6) Contract vs solicitation dispute (2) Contractor responsibility (20) Conviction (4) Cooperative purchasing (3) Corrective action (1) Cost and pricing (13) Debarment (4) Determinations (8) Determining responsibility (37) Disclosure requirements (7) Discussions during solicitation (10) Disposal of surplus property (3) Effective enforcement requirement (35) Effective procurement management (5) Effective specifications (36) Emergency procurement (14) eProcurement (5) Equitable tolling (2) Evaluation of submissions (22) Fair and equitable treatment (14) Fair and reasonable value (23) Fiscal effect of procurement (14) Frivolous protest (1) Good governance (12) Governmental functions (27) Guam (14) Guam procurement law (12) Improper influence (11) Incumbency (13) Integrity of system (31) Interested party (7) Jurisdiction (1) Justification (1) Life-cycle cost (1) Limits of government contracting (5) Lore vs Law (4) market research (7) Materiality (3) Methods of source selection (33) Mistakes (4) Models of Procurement (1) Needs assessment (11) No harm no foul? (8) Offer & acceptance (1) Other procurement links (14) Outsourcing (34) Past performance (12) Planning policy (34) Politics of procurement (52) PPPs (6) Prequalification (1) Principle of competition (95) Principles of procurement (25) Private vs public contract (17) Procurement authority (5) Procurement controversies series (79) Procurement ethics (19) Procurement fraud (31) Procurement lifecycle (9) Procurement philosophy (17) Procurement procedures (30) Procurement reform (63) Procurement theory (11) Procurement workforce (2) Procurment philosophy (6) Professionalism (17) Protest - formality (2) Protest - timing (12) Protests - general (37) Purposes and policies of procurement (11) Recusal (1) Remedies (17) Requirement for new procurement (4) Resolution of protests (4) Responsiveness (14) Restrictive specifications (5) Review procedures (13) RFQ vs RFP (1) Scope of contract (16) Settlement (2) Social preference provisions (60) Sole source (48) Sovereign immunity (3) Staffing (8) Standard commercial products (3) Standards of review (2) Standing (6) Stays and injunctions (6) Structure of procurement (1) Substantiation (9) Surety (1) Suspension (6) The procurement record (1) The role of price (10) The subject matter of procurement (23) Trade agreements vs procurement (1) Training (33) Transparency (63) Uniformity (6) Unsolicited proposals (3)

Tuesday, October 29, 2013

Outsourcing: public service motive vs profit motive?

The following article doesn't provide as many answers, or analysis, as questions and opinion, but the questions are good ones to ponder. It is important because over the last few decades there has been an historic shift from a predominant shift from procurement of things to procurement of services, and the best model for procurement of services is far from conclusive. Read the article at the link; I've only cut and pasted and rearranged parts here.

Why Private Contractors Are Lousy at Public Services
Excluding military personnel, the percentage of all employed people who are U.S. government employees has fallen from 4.3 percent in 1966 to 2 percent today (add in the military, and that would drop from more than 8 percent to about 3 percent). That’s not because the government is a smaller part of the economy. For every federal employee, there are [now] two people working on government contracts.

Private, competitive provision can be considerably more effective than monopoly public provision. In theory, competitive contracting should introduce private sector efficiencies to bloated, public-owned enterprises. Cross-country experience suggests that, on average, performance under private management is a little better than under public management; private provision is associated with bigger networks that lose less power and collect more bills. A look at outsourcing’s track record around the world backs what the [ObamaCare] website’s snafus suggest: Turning over the delivery of government services to private contractors can cause as many problems as when governments provide those services themselves.

The difference, however, is small compared with the efficiency gap between poor and rich countries. The choice can be ugly: Bureaucrats with limited incentive to deliver and sclerotic ability to reform on the one side; weak regulation of private companies that know more about winning a contract than delivering services on the other. Since private and public provision both have weaknesses, surely the worst model is to attempt some mutant hybrid of the two: Private sector providers operating under layers of labyrinthine government regulatory and procurement processes. That, in a nutshell, describes the U.S. health-care system.

No comments: